Key Recommendations
Recommendations for System Design and Implementation
- Implement transit and bicycle improvements prior to starting congestion pricing.
- Adopt specific objectives and metrics to meet traffic, environmental, and health goals and ensure that benefits are equitably shared.
- Design the system to incorporate new technologies that can transition to more dynamic and effective pricing.
- Install congestion pricing devices to allow for a simple method of identifying vehicles bypassing the zone.
- Introduce two-way tolling in the congestion zone.
Recommendations for Pricing
- Vary the congestion fee by the level of congestion at different times of day, and by size of vehicle.
- Set the congestion charge high enough to meet both congestion and revenue targets.
- Apply a consistent rationale to determine which tolls should count as a credit toward the congestion charge.
- Exempt taxis and other for-hire vehicles from the congestion charge, but keep the current surcharge on fares within the congestion zone.
- Limit user-based exemptions to those already specified by the legislature.
![Congestion Pricingshutterstock 138864413](https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/300/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=21e5d754e3d8d0bbd2e86c898041e18dd1534471cee463fd89624d6bd26eead5 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/600/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=c68837701cca3d7148f9962681a044ae1e128fbfb00eb78c3f790340eebb61e5 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/900/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=50a6a7f044bccbdfa2b4f539513a2d20c6b53f402c100b51836c78a387186c18 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1200/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=89f822292caa62a8107714235d9771e08170378c41a555f1bcd13c11f557bbe7 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1500/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=4c8b69cbb8765d222bc0b45b5126dbfbcdac92b6e2248d5c25309f9388f9388d 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1800/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=a90ed117bd32effc701afb6a34141c002dcc725c77a9d57ee0559d7ba01d5e6e 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2100/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=6b6f4e7353b51cd340badacd2294df193704c17337f2e6c5a5dfd773ce6a34dd 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2400/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=4c97cc76813e23657f8658b5609b4f25a056b4ff5fb8b67630fe808c286b76d2 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2700/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_138864413.jpg?bossToken=fe065754744d263092d9e338b67bc962a22f13156cdb7cc993d56500067578d6 1543w)
What’s Included
The legislation authorizing New York’s congestion pricing program specifies several features that must be incorporated:
- The boundaries of the zone as shown in the map below
- An operation date no sooner than December 31, 2020
- A testing period of at least 30 days and a public information campaign of at least 60 days prior to the operation date
- The MTA’s Triborough Bridge and Tunnel Authority (TBTA) as the entity responsible for implementing and maintaining the new tolling system
- A Memorandum of Understanding between MTA and the City of New York specifying how they will work together
- A six-person Traffic Mobility Review Board (TMRB) — five appointed by TBTA and one by the Mayor — to provide recommendations between November 15 and December 31, 2020, or 30 days before the program will go into effect, whenever is sooner
- $100 million allocated from the state budget for installing new tolling technology and infrastructure
- Annual revenue must be sufficient to bond $15 billion in capital spending for the 2020-2024 MTA capital plan
- Passenger cars may only be charged once daily for entering or remaining in the zone
- Revenue will be placed in a lock-box fund, 80% of which will go to NYC subways, buses, and Staten Island Rapid Transit, 10% to Long Island Rail Road, and 10% to Metro-North Railroad
- Emergency vehicles and vehicles transporting disabled persons will be exempt from the charge
- Residents of the zone with incomes less than $60,000 per year will receive a tax credit equal to the amount paid in congestion charges
What’s Not Included
The TBTA, considering non-binding recommendations from the TMRB, will determine all other program features, including the following:
- The mechanism, technology, and location of devices used to identify and charge vehicles entering the zone
- The amount of the congestion charge, including any variations in price by time of day or day of the week
- Any additional exemptions, credits, or discounts
- Metrics or systems for monitoring or evaluating the program
The MTA, through its capital program, will determine which specific projects will be funded.
Our Work Was Guided By The Following Principles:
- Relieving congestion, the original rationale for congestion pricing, is as important as raising revenue for transit, and should be a primary goal of program design. Greenhouse gas and air pollution reduction is also critical given adoption of the Climate Leadership and Community Protection Act.
- The charging system and its rules should be as simple and transparent as possible, with charging and monitoring equipment as unobtrusive as technology allows.
- The cost of entering and leaving the congestion zone should be uniform at all entry and exit points. This ensures that all drivers will be treated equitably and eliminates the incentive for “toll shopping.”
- Prices should be highest when congestion is greatest.
- Larger vehicles have a larger impact and should be charged more.
- To maintain system integrity, maximize revenue and congestion benefits, and fairly distribute benefits and costs among users, exemptions for specific classes of users should be as limited as possible.
- To prevent abuse of the program, strong enforcement measures should be implemented.
- Set prices high enough to cover system costs and to ensure that congestion reduction and revenue goals are met.
- The system should be designed to enable future technological improvements and still more effective pricing policies.
![Congestion Pricing Cover Photo Cropped](https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/300x300/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=89e65ebcbd45c7e4aa127db7c261464a00770acb579232acf25f464bdc2037f5 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/600x600/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=6b428d5a54652f863d2e7f0d1fb13e4805b48ea876ffef720d7d3d6cf64b3f9c 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/900x900/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=3b27eb93abe9ac9c7ebe21438619897b1b97250a4ee0be45c3010054139e397b 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/1200x1200/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=98c2a3da075fcc45df200bd305a4977f6a974e66ff00709e89e1520a439a7559 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/1500x1500/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=4754575b994aab08cad0e94ca3c8bcf24ecb7d1a669a125fcc7bf583f104ec72 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/1800x1800/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=258cc33ebce54a2e23e781c7b0cf4223d79a91995cd7328edd05ff2a7356a5b7 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/2100x2100/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=e84ed0c7f97d6571a3dd80e7bd6e38c49dac9e2eaccc6c2a4434c5cb66d381fc 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/2400x2400/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=791ff59c5c342dd820b31384845d1557380f1ea22db7b072579c386d76e02516 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/2700x2700/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCoverPhoto_Cropped.jpg?bossToken=1076cb662d4353902a95a630d66185220df15923d8925764d63bbcd152b7e622 1543w)
The analysis and recommendations in this report suggest a set of choices that increase equity and foster a more rational transportation system while meeting the outcomes mandated in the legislation.
Getting it Right
RPA makes the following recommendations to the TMRB and TBTA. While recognizing the immediate challenge of getting a well-functioning system up and running, these proposals are intended to advance a fair and effective congestion pricing program that will help rationalize the region’s tolling system.
![Congestion Pricing IMG 6677](https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/300x300/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=52699044f9d563dbc9cb7f22952589a3962498f0e58b595f3f94886e54726bb9 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/600x600/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=511d456fbec82d1f4ce8004404bd3ef66d93022dd7264abdd4e7e3d405134f4d 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/900x900/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=9b0db7763c48b60faf99aae2b8320ad5b031a9bb145217f7a953b9582083d555 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/1200x1200/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=cbecc2b055444835c628fcde535a4e5bb4295e71db7ed973391d26acfc806f63 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/1500x1500/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=455ee9040a887a0051b8157b1f58308f263044ccf8fc92dc036279548e6fc803 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/1800x1800/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=4f7238be6cec19bd7af9c94eb572108f24ee0cafbdc30373304c61f46d828c8e 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/2100x2100/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=0a551feda1291e09debb16460f30cf91eada27bd5b368e8a7274f6044700519e 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/2400x2400/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=9d50a33946101f11db0cb92f1d5fe7b7a6450d88a1971a70bc1724c86e9032d6 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/cover/2700x2700/fp-x:0.5,fp-y:0.5,quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_6677.jpg?bossToken=ad21fb4018e78adacbbde3ffc4f9726a7b543ce0d0e4a6a6096292bdf2eda8a8 1543w)
Recommendations for System Design and Implementation
- Implement transit and bicycle improvements prior to starting congestion pricing.
Providing better transit options will make the program’s launch more successful. While the MTA is facing financial challenges, it could use existing revenues from for-hire vehicle fees to improve bus service in the near term, as London did before congestion pricing went into effect. Streets could also be prioritized for buses. More protected bicycle routes and bikeshare docks, including those with electric bikes, near entry points and on both sides of the East River would also help. - Adopt specific objectives and metrics to meet traffic, environmental, and health goals and ensure that benefits are equitably shared.
Recognizing congestion reduction is just as important as raising revenue, the TBTA should specify program targets for traffic reduction, vehicle counts, vehicle miles traveled, air pollution, and other metrics as recommended in the Fix NYC Advisory Panel Report, and make these goals public. Metrics and monitoring should measure neighborhood impacts, and transit improvements should prioritize neighborhoods with fewer transit options, lower household incomes, and disproportionate pollution impacts. - Design the system to incorporate new technologies that can transition to more dynamic and effective pricing.
The simplest technology to implement is the E-ZPass system, which has been highly successful over its 25-plus years. Camera systems and license plate recognition (LPR) software are prevalent in existing congestion pricing applications and would be required here to accommodate users without E-ZPass. Nevertheless, E-ZPass does not make use of the new technologies that can identify locations and routes.
Planning should begin now for a congestion pricing program technology upgrade to eventually replace the E-ZPass system. The goal should be to replace the lump-sum charges with a more nuanced approach that charges vehicles in proportion to time or distance spent in the most congested locations. New technology could be applied to for-hire vehicles first and then expanded to commercial vehicle fleets and eventually to passenger cars. This will also enable the congestion charge to eventually be incorporated into a region-wide system that could replace tolls and other fees with charges on the number of miles or hours a vehicle traveled, resulting in a fairer and more effective system for managing traffic and maintaining transportation infrastructure. - Install congestion pricing devices to allow for a simple method of identifying vehicles bypassing the zone.
To avoid installing dozens of congestion pricing devices to identify vehicles that travel only on the FDR or West Side Highway without entering the zone, use devices placed at bridges, tunnels, and at 60th Street to record when a vehicle enters and leaves using these highways. The congestion fee can then be dropped if the vehicle leaves within a short period of time, indicating that they used the highways for through travel without entering the zone. - Introduce two-way tolling in the congestion zone.
To eliminate toll shopping and better manage congestion, the cost of entering or leaving the congestion zone should be consistent. This is best accomplished by implementing the congestion fee as a two-way charge, as TBTA facilities do now, rather than only charging in one direction. By charging for both portions of a trip – entering and leaving the zone – the variable tolls will have more influence on driver behavior, incentivizing drivers to shift their trips out of the peak period whenever possible. Two-way charges would also permit prices to be tailored to most effectively reduce congestion since the traffic patterns of morning and evening peaks differ.
Recommendations for Pricing
- Vary the congestion fee by the level of congestion at different times of day, and by size of vehicle.
To achieve the most congestion relief, drivers who use the road at the most congested times should be most encouraged to switch to different times or other modes of transportation. Pricing scenarios described in this report show estimated improvements in peak period traffic speeds ranging from a 10% traffic speed increase in a scenario with a flat daytime congestion fee to a 16% speed increase in a scenario with sharply peaked tolls. The scenario with the higher peak period price would reduce the number of hours in traffic by 12% more than the flat fee alternative, even though the total fees collected from motorists would only be 6% greater. Each of these scenarios would raise comparable revenue. The potential congestion relief argues for a robust system of variable pricing driven by the substantial differences in congestion at different times. As they do on existing tolled facilities, large trucks should pay more than smaller vehicles to account for their greater impact on infrastructure, health, and the environment. - Set the congestion charge high enough to meet both congestion and revenue targets.
The congestion charge should be sufficient to meet specific traffic and capital investment targets, either by budgeting for contingencies in case estimates are low or by including a mechanism to adjust prices if needed. - Apply a consistent rationale to determine which tolls should count as a credit toward the congestion charge.
If no one receives a credit for tolls that they currently pay for traveling to the congestion zone, we would recreate the current inefficient and unfair system in which some drivers pay much more than others, and traffic is exacerbated as people drive extra miles to find the cheapest route. Determining which tolls to credit is a difficult question, but should be based on a consistent rationale that does the most to equalize tolls for drivers with similar trips, reduce incentives to drive farther and add congestion in order to avoid higher tolls, and limit revenue reductions that would be passed on to other drivers. Since the interactions of tolls and the congestion fee will vary depending on whether the fee is one-way or two-way, and what type of variable pricing structure is applied, decisions on which tolls to credit could be deferred until the program design and pricing structure are determined. - Exempt taxis and other for-hire vehicles from the congestion charge, but keep the current surcharge on fares within the congestion zone.
The current surcharge for trips taken in these vehicles is a more effective method, for both managing congestion and reaching the revenue target. Regardless of the congestion charge, for-hire vehicle drivers must enter the zone to work, but the per trip charge gives passengers an incentive to walk, bike, or take transit. The per trip charge also raises an estimated $400 million per year which would be lost if the charge were to be replaced with an entry fee. - Limit user-based exemptions to those already specified by the legislature.
The legislation exempts several classes of users. Unfortunately, even these mandated exemptions are open to abuse, and must be rigorously enforced with substantial penalties for violators. NY Legislature should consider legislation that clarifies the exemption for persons with disabilities and creates a clear enforcement mechanism to reduce potential abuse. The exemption for emergency vehicles should not be permitted to open the door for misuse by government workers as has been done with windshield placards to get free parking. Since multiple trips by passenger vehicles are exempt, the TMRB should study the revenue, congestion, and economic impacts of multiple trips for small commercial vehicles. However, this should only be considered if multiple charging is found to result in substantial hardship and negative impacts.
Congestion pricing is intended to benefit car users by reducing congestion; transit riders by investing in subways, buses and commuter rails; and communities by reducing air pollution and improving health outcomes. It is also an economically progressive policy.
Across the region, there is a clear income disparity between households that own cars and those that do not. In every county, car-owning households report at least double the income of non-car owning households. For example, Brooklyn households with cars make twice as much as households without. In the Bronx, that ratio is 2.5, in Nassau County it is 3.5, and in Bergen County it is 3 times as much. In New York City overall, more than half of households do not own private vehicles. By reducing traffic, the congestion fee benefits those who pay it. By investing collected revenue into public transportation, congestion pricing will help address existing inequities throughout the city and region.
The Community Service Society found that just four percent of outer borough NYC residents drive into Manhattan for work, while 56% rely on public transportation to get to jobs in Manhattan and elsewhere. Just two percent of the working poor would potentially pay a congestion charge.
Pricing Alternatives
To test the effects of different pricing strategies, RPA used the Balanced Transportation Analyzer (BTA), a robust modeling tool developed by Charles Komanoff to estimate the impacts of various congestion pricing proposals. At the core of this model is a series of linked spreadsheets that generate a wide range of output measures based on well-documented sources of data and research. Inputs include pricing levels for different times of day, and different types of surcharges and exemptions. Outputs include revenues raised, toll and surcharge incidence by geography, traffic volumes, traffic speeds, air quality, and health impacts.
The BTA was also used by the Fix NYC Advisory Panel to estimate the impacts of pricing strategies. The scenarios developed for this report build on the Fix NYC analysis by exploring a wider range of variable pricing scenarios and additional output variables. These scenarios are not completely comparable to the Fix NYC results. The results shown here use different assumptions, incorporating updated toll prices and the exemptions included in the enabling legislation.
The four scenarios presented below were designed to be consistent with the principles outlined in the beginning of this report, and to test the revenue and traffic impacts of pricing alternatives that are based on existing TBTA tolls.
They range from a scenario that assumes a flat fare equal to the current TBTA toll to one in which the peak fare is 50% higher than the TBTA toll and the off-peak fare is 50% lower. All four assume that weekday nights and weekend days, when congestion is less, are half the TBTA fare, and weekend nights, when congestion is least, are free. Commercial vehicle fees were assumed to vary in the same proportion as passenger car fees. Each scenario assumes that vehicles traveling directly into the zone through tolled facilities, or crossing the Robert F Kennedy, George Washington, and Henry Hudson Bridges in upper Manhattan, are credited for the tolls they paid.
![Congestion Pricing Charts Price Curve newcolors 01 01 01](https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/300/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=e6164d74b3cf2e4799f0cc0a091694da4e3af06ab0996f92daabb880fa5fe64e 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/600/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=ab9ff983ff3537af9bb7c6fdb418773e119aa6b0593bdfc4508a8840f755d94d 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/900/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=d963949093e08c00241bf26cc8dd47f9278ffe5b9492dddf3d50718d2255210d 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1200/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=c5cf9dbea85fadf3acc9bc2c2d99558db27c13888725b5ea1f260a4327a6dfdf 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1500/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=b638ddaa0eae2b27a8ca7e99f9136c0a0e52446f9de6ab812d9838b047dd923a 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1800/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=605080d39c04ecc3ac24b81dbb85633aa1c34ead14115c3740a1492a026062d5 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2100/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=b718c624941fd9011b37909b61b76b311111d34a2e86e6c520109362c1bd299d 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2400/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=eae580e200df1c623f237389eb0cdd53f0d1331ebd44623712a2d00c9b0f9951 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2700/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingCharts_PriceCurve_newcolors-01-01-01.png?bossToken=6306fb34f2de0925adc3a5437d54764e7cbf69754a056586e2eed410876f6e34 1543w)
Alternative congestion pricing scenarios
Prices indicate the congestion charge for autos. The charge for trucks is assumed to be 2.5 times auto charge. The revenue estimates include an estimated loss of 4% from the legislated exemptions for emergency vehicles, persons with disabilities, and multiple trips per day by passenger cars. Since the model has not yet been adjusted to account for vehicles that bypass the congestion zone on the FDR and West Street, an additional $30 million was deducted based on calculations in technical memorandum: Potential Location of Congestion Pricing Devices. Gross revenues were then reduced by $113 million operating costs estimated for a two-way charge.
![Congestion Pricingshutterstock 1127550593](https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/300/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=940a629a4aac9c5be15528b172742334ea8bec3a18810f13d1193f9e1fd33de5 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/600/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=5d66fbc3cab8f00cadb2c276dfeb50a5e355a3deb1758cb411f010fcf904c634 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/900/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=643f74e81851b0e6b15ae3ead98b8e304ebb6a906ab53a8e9d2d2f2abe36b645 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1200/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=f89acf1088f9ca13bb4633e33c06dd030c99d2b6024f082aa3e9394f7958eac2 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1500/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=0022c220ba53868aaf000895d39a274cb375b3ff7cfcf77e1d743792348b958e 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1800/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=a8b7d2889118418b994b14c27860451693af3ad556fdef5d2b8597caad44da31 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2100/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=d3487aee1096d6e729a41847257d7732ca591d1414fd124350b21ad618a13d7c 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2400/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=17c163d9eb8f204eb192495c149376c9ba17ad9b62c95206f76f5e91454d4710 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2700/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_1127550593_200425_173219.jpg?bossToken=4cced76fc77b660becc8b0d67429139806c375f0a3868e4ac85a124ff01c45f0 1543w)
Traffic, Revenue, Environmental, and Health Impacts of Pricing Alternatives
Revenue Impacts
All four scenarios yield similar levels of net revenue ranging from $1.0-1.1 billion annually. The results demonstrate that all four could produce enough revenue to meet the $1 billion net revenue target. This suggests that there is flexibility for meeting the revenue target with different price assumptions. However, actual costs and driver behavior could differ from model predictions for a number of reasons, and pricing policies should provide reasonable certainty that revenues will cover bond payments for $15 billion in capital expenditures.
These scenarios show that raising peak prices and lowering off-peak prices by similar amounts raises similar amounts of revenue, while yielding better congestion benefits. Even highly peaked pricing schedules can be designed to be revenue neutral relative to pricing at a flat rate.
For illustration purposes, all of these scenarios used the same assumptions for night and weekend prices. Varying these prices could also change revenues significantly. For example, making weekday nights free instead of half the TBTA toll would decrease revenues by $70 million. Increasing weekend day fees to equal TBTA tolls would increase revenues by $150 million. It would also be desirable to differentiate truck fees by size and type of vehicle to account for different impacts on congestion and road maintenance costs.
![Congestion Pricingshutterstock 140240308](https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/300/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=80bc977a7452622806839e2bfc9b5b01d0cdd032e0a3c564d0088ded19fa6c8e 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/600/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=518d7f6f4b2d10308ddc1ce92c469ae7942b4704a41732fac55f69228e90f5c5 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/900/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=951022740f73c8e133f29adbc552a47e2064edc1473630c1af752153ba654fa3 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1200/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=a65708baa4a3fcf71e2f4a1e650eafa018f1a8e399ad1e84ec2ac73eb9ee77fe 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1500/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=406fdeacf84a9830763040a5a241962404529360b210992ff1e1b239c9d48098 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1800/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=9085159786d832f013cc7263668038461aa7333da8d226d872e207a513b4fa3a 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2100/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=c061998ed4a04a5c599e10b239a40a36adf040aa7631290858253a4fd0bd308a 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2400/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=8ffa5e9ae51f863c81069212a21ca3a001b9fd9f116a42b363d2466301659f44 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2700/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_140240308.jpg?bossToken=f4d01c2b8d8d7dcdbb9a2ff1184505d502b22ac82ced6f137f99cb18c150e316 1543w)
Traffic Impacts
The scenarios produce significant differences in congestion relief. Even this improvement in average traffic speeds can make a big difference, with greater reliability and less time spent in stalled traffic.
The more the prices vary between peak and off-peak, the greater the benefits during high congestion periods.
Speeds increase by 12% in the peak with mildly peaked prices, 14% with moderately peaked and 16% with highly peaked. These estimates are conservative, as the model does not account for the additional congestion reduction effect of two-way charging. Speed increases are progressively less in the off-peak, but these times are far less congested overall.
Currently, vehicles travel only 6.35 miles per hour (mph) on average in peak periods compared to 10.19 mph outside of the peak. Scenario D, with a high differential between peak and off-peak prices, would improve the average peak period speed to an estimated 7.34 mph and off-peak speed to 10.36 mph. Not only would average peak speeds be closer to what they currently are at less congested times of day, but travel times would be more predictable, with less time in stalled traffic and fewer extremes when trips take substantially longer.
The total amount of time saved, for both the peak and off-peak periods combined, rises with peak pricing. Drivers save an estimated 152,000 hours each weekday in the highly peaked scenario, 12% more than with a flat rate. On the other hand, there is little difference in the total number of cars entering the congestion zone or the number of vehicle miles traveled between the scenarios. This follows from the expectation that many drivers will shift to a less congested time of day, rather than forgoing the trip altogether.
Even with conservative estimates, these time savings alone could be worth the equivalent of over $1.5 billion per year.
Environmental and Health Impacts
Congestion pricing will help clean the air and reduce respiratory-related illness and disease. It would also help to meet emissions reductions requirements set by the Climate Leadership and Community Protection Act. The scenario comparisons indicate that most of these benefits will come from a reduction in the overall number of cars on the road. Since variable pricing is likely to shift the time of trips more than it reduces their overall numbers, the differences between the scenarios are slight. Both carbon dioxide emissions and small air-borne particles would be reduced by between seven and eight percent in each scenario, while other pollutants like carbon monoxide, nitrogen oxides, and sulfur dioxide would be reduced by between four and five percent. These emission reductions would result in over $100 million in estimated health cost savings annually. The model also projects that each scenario would result in over 750 fewer traffic-related injuries and four fewer deaths each year.
One-Way vs Two-Way Congestion Charge
Crediting Drivers for Tolls
Historically, tolls have been used to build and maintain the region’s transportation infrastructure, including the highways, bridges, and tunnels where the tolls are collected, and the trains, subways, and buses that keep these facilities from being overwhelmed with traffic. The congestion charge is different in that it is designed explicitly to reduce traffic by discouraging driving in and during the most congested part and time of the region. But it is layered on top of both tolled and untolled facilities serving the same area. Many drivers already pay a toll to get to the congestion zone. The existing price structure and the purpose of congestion pricing complicate the goal of equality in price.
Depending on how the congestion charge is applied for trips already paying an existing toll, it can equalize the cost of driving between those who have been paying to come into the congestion zone for years and those who have been driving in for free. However, because the congestion fee must meet the legislated revenue target to support $15 billion in capital expenditures, every toll credit means that the fee needs to be higher on other users to fulfill the revenue goal. In addition, crediting tolls reduces the congestion mitigation effect. This is a potential area of conflict between the revenue goal and the promised traffic mitigation.
Equalizing the cost to enter the congestion zone is important to the success of a congestion pricing program. Without crediting existing tolls, congestion pricing would replicate the inequities of the current toll structure with some drivers who make similar trips paying far more than others. But there is no clear fomula for drawing the line in determining which tolls to credit. In evaluating the merits of different options, facilities can be grouped into three alternatives that have an arguable rationale: crediting tolls on bridges and tunnels connected directly to the zone, crediting all bridges and tunnels connected to Manhattan, and crediting all bridges and tunnels connected to one of the five New York City boroughs. Any tolls beyond this geography are used to support a different part of the transportation system and should be in addition to congestion charges in the region’s core.
The general pros and cons of each of these alternatives are described below based on the following criteria:
- How much it equalizes tolls so that drivers with similar trips pay similar amounts in combined tolls and congestion fees
- What effect it has on vehicle miles traveled and congestion from toll shopping
- How much the overall congestion charge would need to increase to fulfill the revenue target
To fully evaluate the impacts of these alternatives, however, the program design and pricing structure need to be determined first. Driver behavior will vary depending on whether the congestion fee will be a one-way or two-way charge, and how the fee will vary by time of day. For illustrative purposes, the following page shows what drivers would pay under different crediting options assuming two-way tolling and the differential pricing assumptions from Scenario C shown in the Alternative congestion pricing scenarios table above. In this scenario, all drivers would pay more in the peak period even if they receive a credit, since the round trip peak period charge is higher than both the TBTA and PA tolls. Outside of the peak period, when the congestion charge is lower, most drivers receiving a toll credit would not pay an additional congestion charge. Those using the Henry Hudson Bridge or other facilities with lower tolls would pay a small increment in the off-peak.
Impacts on revenues would be driven by the number of vehicles and the toll amounts for each crossing. More than 200,000 passenger cars, representing about 30% of all autos entering the congestion zone, pay a toll to directly enter the congestion zone using either a TBTA or PA tunnel. An even greater number, about 34% of the total, come over one of the free East River bridges. Ten percent cross at 60th Street after paying a toll at the RFK, George Washington or Henry Hudson Bridges. The remaining 26% cross at 60th Street after originating in upper Manhattan or crossing into upper Manhattan via a free bridge from Queens or the Bronx. About two percent of all vehicles entering the congestion zone crossed a tolled bridge in the outer boroughs on their way to the Manhattan. Most of these currently use a free crossing to enter Manhattan, but some use one of the tolled crossings.
Illustration of Toll Crediting Options
The three cases below describe the pros and cons of different options for crediting drivers for tolls payed on the way to and from Manhattan. The charts describe what drivers would pay to get in and out of Manhattan in each case using the $16.35 ($8.15 in each direction) peak time congestion fee proposed in Scenario C in the table above.
Case 1: Credit Crossings Entering Congestion Zone
Crediting tolls for the four tunnels connected directly to the congestion zone would create parity for the drivers using those facilities with those who currently pay no toll. If combined with two-way charging, it would eliminate toll shopping at the East River crossings. These credits are equivalent to $340 million in annual revenue using pricing Scenario C from the Alternative congestion pricing scenarios table. However, drivers coming over the upper Manhattan bridges would pay as much as twice as much to travel to the congestion zone as everyone else. Many of these drivers are likely to divert to tunnels or bridges where they could receive a credit. This would be a particular concern at the already congested Lincoln Tunnel, affecting not only cars and trucks but also bus operations in and out of the Port Authority Bus Terminal. It would also be likely to push more drivers to the Queens-Midtown Tunnel and untolled crossings from Queens and the Bronx.
- Equalizes tolls for nearly 90% of entrants to the zone,
but over 80,000 drivers could pay as much as double what others pay - Eliminates toll shopping incentives for many drivers
but maintains or increases incentives for drivers entering from west of the Hudson, the Bronx and parts of Queens - Congestion fee could approximate current TBTA toll
and raise $1 billion
Case 2: Credit Crossings Entering Manhattan
The main argument for crediting all crossings into Manhattan is that it would result in nearly all congestion zone-bound drivers paying the same amount. There is little to distinguish drivers crossing at the George Washington Bridge from those crossing through the Lincoln and Holland tunnels, and those taking the RFK Bridge from those taking the Queens-Midtown tunnel. They are paying the same toll for similar facilities and their revenues are used for the same purpose. Henry Hudson Bridge tolls are lower, but the same principles apply. Incentives for toll shopping would be largely eliminated. The main disadvantage is that it would require an increase in the congestion charge to meet the revenue target. The charge would need to be 9% higher to yield comparable revenues.
- Equalizes tolls for nearly all entrants to the zone
- Eliminates or reduces most toll shopping incentives
- Congestion fee would have to be 8-10% higher than Case 1
Case 3: Credit Crossings Entering Manhattan or within New York City
Extending the credit to all bridges and tunnels in the five boroughs would cover the remaining two percent of congestion zone-bound drivers, and have only a small impact on revenues compared with crediting Manhattan crossings. However, all of these drivers have to cross a second bridge or tunnel to get into Manhattan, and there is an argument that they should pay somewhat more for their cost of their trip.
- All entrants to the zone would pay the same amount, although users of outer bridges would use two crossings
- Eliminates or reduces most toll shopping incentives
- Congestion fee would have to be 10-12% higher than Case 1
User-Based Exemptions
Any discounts or exemptions granted to particular classes of users will erode the revenue and congestion mitigation impacts of the program, and increase the burden on non-exempt users. The exemptions specified in the legislation are already estimated to reduce overall revenues by about 4% per year. Weak enforcement and tolerance of tampering to avoid paying will result in even greater losses.
The emergency vehicle exemption needs clearly defined and easily enforced guidelines so other government or quasi-government vehicles, or vehicles used by government employees for private purposes, pay the congestion charge. The widely abused parking placard system, whereby government employees park indiscriminately using widely available, sometimes counterfeit, placards, is a lesson in what can occur with weak enforcement. The implementation of the congestion pricing program is an opportunity to strengthen measures to prevent placard and license plate abuse and congestion pricing avoidance.
Persons with disabilities are exempt from the congestion fee. This exemption is difficult to enforce and is prone to abuse when vehicles are shared. The NY Legislature should consider legislation that clarifies this exemption and creates a clear enforcement mechanism to reduce potential abuse.
Most other exemptions that have been proposed are not justified by any undue hardship or larger societal benefit. However, two that deserve consideration are exemptions for for-hire vehicles and multiple trips by commercial vehicles.
![Congestion Pricing IMG 7273 cropped](https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/300/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=f681a116ccccc14abaf4b92c965ae687f7bc313f2b7352bb73089eb35d35f164 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/600/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=29e9fb2b03ead76588eee59d9cd60d0eabd5ac663107514efe22dd778f721d0c 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/900/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=56b96c5326157b20cc067f0398a1bbb3bd73c72eb8a308a7e397a8c7b318e100 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1200/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=e5a5ee29bd50a699fe1d54eee8b05e498a406e3674689e9794a2d51e717787df 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1500/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=49567cd40e2a6f64dd98fbe49c38b8a930850687b872baaeaa80b973e7eac3b0 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1800/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=5ac28bf61732883adcc9898054892ba12c3fc8537440506627bdc4674804999e 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2100/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=745886119e100d2049c97a38cc272071cb83763c7f90c9290a85dc5a6fcac558 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2400/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=24785f0430d866db57987839b6c976a9b0e68082690eabe97d11b8c58f4ec945 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2700/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-PricingIMG_7273_cropped.jpg?bossToken=226a8706ecc039074360968743656cf7b3bbb0b3acc6a6eea4c6ce7e4bb2b513 1543w)
For-hire vehicles — taxis, car service vehicles and cars using app-based services by transportation network companies (TNCs) currently pay a surcharge for trips within, to, from, or passing through a zone from 96th Street south in Manhattan. It is reasonable to exempt these vehicles from the congestion charge while keeping the surcharge in place. The surcharge is $2.50 for yellow cabs, and $2.75 for green cabs and TNCs. It is estimated to raise over $400 million a year for the MTA, while levying the congestion charge on these vehicles would yield over $100 million. The revenue from the surcharge is in addition to the $1 billion that needs to be raised from the congestion charge, so substituting the congestion charge for the surcharge would mean $400 million less in revenue for transit. The surcharge for these trips is also more likely to have the effect on individual passenger choices that congestion pricing is meant to have than will the congestion charge — i.e. a livery driver will not think twice about their “mode” to the congestion zone. But if individuals facing a new cost structure choose alternate modes within the zone, in time the supply of livery vehicles would readjust to meet the demand.
Whether to exempt multiple trips by commercial vehicles, as passenger cars will be, is less clear cut. Forgiving the cost of the multiple trips would soften the impact on small businesses, and it would be consistent to treat passenger and commercial vehicles similarly. However, business is one of the greatest beneficiaries of congestion reduction, and small businesses should continue to be incentivized to program trips as efficiently as possible. Further research is needed to determine the congestion, revenue, and economic impacts of extending this exemption to commercial vehicles.
![Congestion Pricingshutterstock 703134193](https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/300/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=21bb705d6088f401c808d60d7f68f7d4de8b5b5f29ac631461be2d2b4c736587 171w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/600/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=0e584da5c038f7a65555e74c6fe0f5b2bb32c07cac1696351e705b973af904dc 343w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/900/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=01ee4a8c3db09ad4c0a9c46866f3a6efa48377827f01957d5e45a10b629aa6ea 514w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1200/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=ec603ce74d5d5d60fd64f3e9f0e15c3844f5f2b725528f65e0c2afb303dd3973 686w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1500/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=cfcdc3b3e7f9c6eb93e6ada6157f2713beef5bb962f1b48f4d51ba24b355587b 857w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/1800/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=8c0bbcb1771dd14153ececb32e474e759dfd13f20b10fe0c5e3ec93f911b5d11 1029w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2100/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=6e23b27dc1469ee817c9bf3e50a5f24e03d66d6ac45e651582614f4d9c3b4c09 1200w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2400/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=e729c234dc01ec2a4e1116829efee900f363b13c362d647d3c12bfa41832a4af 1371w, https://img.imageboss.me/general/width/2700/quality:80/work/Reports/2019-Reports/Congestion-Pricing-in-NYC/Congestion-Pricingshutterstock_703134193.jpg?bossToken=2965bbc942c91ca8f599bea672f8c5ba51d482c6dc7ee422d4ab00332099cd32 1543w)
Next Steps
After decades of discussing the merits of congestion pricing, New York finally has the opportunity to see how the proposal not only transforms our transportation network, but also the way people live and move in and around the City.
We’ve seen congestion pricing be a game changer for cities around the world. And now, New York has the critical chance to take a major step forward towards a world class transportation network.
But passing congestion pricing is just the beginning. Many hard and controversial decisions lay ahead.
If implemented properly, congestion pricing will be groundbreaking. It will allow us to unclog our streets, improve quality of life and health, help meet state clean air goals, and raise much-needed revenue for our public transportation system. And it will set a model for other cities across the country and world struggling with congestion, air pollution, and aging infrastructure.
The next 15 months will prove to be a critical time as proposals arise and begin to shape what the program looks like. And while the legislation created a framework for a congestion pricing program that prominently positions revenue goals, it is equally as important to set congestion relief targets, and ensure public and environmental health remain priorities.
The new program has the chance to solve Manhattan’s complex and inequitable toll shopping system. The revenue generated from this program will be an important piece in funding the largest transit system in the world. But we need to get it right.
Now the real work begins.
Acknowledgements
Authored by
Special thanks:
- While the content and accuracy of this report is strictly the responsibility of RPA, we wish to thank Mary Barber, Charles Komanoff, Alex Matthiessen, Danny Pearlstein, Sam Schwartz, and Julie Tighe for their contributions. NYC DOT, MTA, Port Authority of New York and New Jersey, and RPA’s New York and New Jersey state committees also provided input.
Other Reports in this Series
531